'A Long History of a Short Block'
by Brian Bamford
IN a recent essay in the FT Weekend Magazine Tim Harford,
the undercover economist, wrote that 'the
nation state is a political unit, not an economic one', and while 'national authorities can impose a common
interest rate, tax rates and regulations' through which political policy
influences the economy, it can be argued that the natural unit of macroeconomic
analysis is not the nation state, but the city, the region, and the surrounding
areas.
In posts on this NV
Blog Les May has argued about the necessity of a National Health
Service and national, if not international, standardisation of electrical
supply such as equal voltages. John
Desmond has argued that a more local system would be possible in certain circumstances referring to Spanish sources (see below Review of Anarchist Voices by Les May and other related posts).
New research by three development economists, William Easterly, Laura Freschi and Steven Pennings has produced a paper 'A Long History of a Short Block' in which they examined the economic development of a single 486ft. block of Greene Street between Houston and Prince Street in downtown Manhattan. Easterly is well known for his scepticism about how much development can ever be planned, and how much credit can political leaders and their so-called expert advisers claim when things go well.
New research by three development economists, William Easterly, Laura Freschi and Steven Pennings has produced a paper 'A Long History of a Short Block' in which they examined the economic development of a single 486ft. block of Greene Street between Houston and Prince Street in downtown Manhattan. Easterly is well known for his scepticism about how much development can ever be planned, and how much credit can political leaders and their so-called expert advisers claim when things go well.
William Easterly
argues:
'Here's a block where there is no leader;
there's no president or prime minister of this block', and Greene Street, he says, offers us a
perspective on the more spontaneous, decentralised features of economic
development.
The study of the
history of Greene Street offers a series swift and surprising changes. The Dutch colonised Manhattan in 1624, but
decided to cede what is now New York to the British in 1667, in exchange for
guarantees over the possession of what is now Suriname in Latin America. At that time this sugar-rich region looked a
good thing, but now New York City's economy is a hundred times bigger than
Suriname's.
In 1850, Greene Street
was a prosperous residential district with some households that would be
millionaires by today's standards. Two
large hotels and a theatre opened, and prostitutes started to move into the area. By 1870, the middle-classes had shifted, and
the block became the heart of New York City's largest sex-work districts.
Towards the end of the
19th century, perhaps because property values in the red-light area
were low, entrepreneurs came in to build large cast-iron stores and warehouses
for the garment trade. Then Greene
Street's luck ran out when this industry moved uptown after 1910, and property
values collapsed. Urban planners in the
1940s and 1950s suggested bulldozing the area and starting again, but a
campaign by the neighbourhood successfully resisted this. Property values revived as artists began to
colonised Greene Street enticed-in by the low priced large and airy
spaces.
As a lesson of this
Tim Harford suggests that getting the
'basic infrastructure right – streets,
water, sanitation, policing – is a good idea', but 'aggressive planning, knocking down entire blocks in response to
temporary weakness, is probably not.'
In this sense central planning and predicting the process of economic
development at a local level is 'a game
for suckers'.
No comments:
Post a Comment